Joan Robinson

Joan Robinson
Robinson in 1973
Born Joan Violet Maurice
(1903-10-31)31 October 1903
Surrey, England
Died 5 August 1983(1983-08-05) (aged 79)
Cambridge
Nationality British
Field Monetary economics
School or
tradition
Post-Keynesian economics
Influences Karl Marx, John Maynard Keynes, Piero Sraffa, Michał Kalecki
Contributions Joan Robinson's growth model
Amoroso–Robinson relation

Joan Violet Robinson FBA (née Maurice; 31 October 1903 – 5 August 1983) was a British economist well known for her wide-ranging contributions to economic theory. She was a central figure in what became known as post-Keynesian economics.

Biography

Before leaving to fight in the Second Boer War, Joan Maurice's father married Margaret Helen Marsh, the daughter of Frederick Howard Marsh, and the sister of Edward Marsh, at St George's, Hanover Square.[1] Joan Maurice was born in 1903, a year after her father's return from Africa.

She studied economics at Girton College, Cambridge, and while there came under the influence of Maurice Dobb, a member of the Communist Party of Great Britain.[2] "Dobb was probably the first academic in Britain to carry a Communist Party membership card. Without Dobb, communism would never have gained the prominence in Cambridge that it did."[3] However, by no means all of his students agreed with his political views. A group of "hearties" seized him and threw him "fully dressed into the River Cam", in a futile effort to teach him sense. This happened to Dobb more than once; but his persecutors became bored and eventually left him alone.[4]

Immediately after graduation in 1925, she married the economist Austin Robinson. In 1937, she became a lecturer in economics at the University of Cambridge. She joined the British Academy in 1958 and was elected a fellow of Newnham College in 1962. In 1965 she assumed the position of full professor and fellow of Girton College. In 1979, just four years before she died, she became the first female honorary fellow of King's College.

As a member of "the Cambridge School" of economics, Robinson contributed to the support and exposition of Keynes' General Theory, writing especially on its employment implications in 1936 and 1937 (it attempted to explain employment dynamics in the midst of the Great Depression).

Joan Robinson in the 1920s

In 1933 in her book The Economics of Imperfect Competition, Robinson coined the term "monopsony," which is used to describe the buyer converse of a seller monopoly. Monopsony is commonly applied to buyers of labour, where the employer has wage setting power that allows it to exercise Pigouvian exploitation[5] and pay workers less than their marginal productivity. Robinson used monopsony to describe the wage gap between women and men workers of equal productivity.[6]

In 1942 Robinson's An Essay on Marxian Economics famously concentrated on Karl Marx as an economist, helping to revive the debate on this aspect of his legacy.

During the World War II, Robinson worked on a few different Committees for the wartime national government. During this time, she visited the Soviet Union as well as China, gaining an interest in underdeveloped and developing nations.

In 1948 she was appointed the first economist member of the Monopolies and Mergers Commission.[7]

In 1949 she was invited by Ragnar Frisch to become the Vice-President of the Econometric Society but declined, saying she couldn't be part of the editorial committee of a journal she couldn't read.

In 1956 Robinson published her magnum opus, The Accumulation of Capital, which extended Keynesianism into the long-run.

In 1962 she published Essays in the Theory of Economic Growth, another book on growth theory, which discussed Golden Age growth paths. Afterwards she developed the Cambridge growth theory with Nicholas Kaldor. She was elected a Foreign Honorary Member of the American Academy of Arts and Sciences in 1964.[8]

During the 1960s she was a major participant in the Cambridge capital controversy alongside Piero Sraffa.

Near the end of her life she studied and concentrated on methodological problems in economics and tried to recover the original message of Keynes' General Theory. Between 1962 and 1980 she wrote many economics books for the general public. Robinson suggested developing an alternative to the revival of classical economics.

At least two students who studied under her have won the Nobel Prize in Economic Sciences: Amartya Sen and Joseph Stiglitz. In his autobiographical notes for the Nobel Foundation, Stiglitz described their relationship as "tumultuous" and Robinson as unused to "the kind of questioning stance of a brash American student"; after a term, Stiglitz therefore "switched to Frank Hahn".[9] In his own autobiography notes, Sen described Robinson as "totally brilliant but vigorously intolerant".[10]

Robinson was a frequent visitor to Centre for Development Studies (CDS), Thiruvananthapuram, India. She was a Visiting Fellow at the Centre in the mid-1970s. She instituted an endowment fund to support public lectures at the Centre. She was a frequent visitor to the Centre until January, 1982 and participated in all activities of the Centre and especially student seminars. Professor Robinson donated royalties of two of her books (Selected Economic Writings, Bombay: Oxford University Press, 1974, Introduction to Modern Economics (jointly with John Eatwell), Delhi; Tata McGraw Hill, 1974) to CDS.

Also, Robinson made several trips to China, reporting her observations and analyses in China: An Economic Perspective (1958), The Cultural Revolution in China (1969), and Economic Management in China (1975; 3rd edn, 1976), in which she praised the Cultural Revolution. In October 1964, Robinson also visited North Korea, which implemented social reforms and collectivisation at the time, and wrote in her report "Korean Miracle" that the country's success was due to "the intense concentration of the Koreans on national pride" under Kim Il-sung, "a messiah rather than a dictator".[11] She also stated in reference to the division of Korea that "[o]bviously, sooner or later the country must be reunited by absorbing the South into socialism."[12] During her last decade, she became more and more pessimistic about the possibilities of reforming economic theory, as expressed, for example, in her essay "Spring Cleaning".[13]

The Cultural Revolution in China is written from the perspective of trying to understand the thinking that lay behind the revolution, particularly Mao Zedong's preoccupations. Mao is seen as aiming to recapture a revolutionary sense in a population that had known only, or had grown used to, stable Communism, so that it could "re-educate the Party" (pp. 20, 27); to instil a realisation that the people needed the guidance of the Party and much as the other way round (p. 20); to re-educate intellectuals who failed to see that their role in society, like that of all other groups, was to 'Serve the People' (pp. 33, 43); and finally to secure a succession, not stage-managed by the Party hierarchy or even by Mao himself but the product of interaction between a revitalised people and a revitalised Party (p. 26).

On the whole, the book emphasises the positive aspects of Mao's "moderate and humane" intentions (p. 19) rather than the "violence and disorder" that broke out, we are told, "from time to time", occurrences "strongly opposed" (ibid.) to Mao's wishes. Robinson recognises and appears to endorse a revision to classical Marxism in Mao's view of the relation of base to superstructure: "On the classical view, there is one-way determination between base and superstructure but Mao shows how the superstructure may react upon the base: Ideas may become a material force" (p. 12). She acknowledges that "Old-fashioned Marxists might regard this as a heresy, but that is scarcely reasonable" (ibid.).

Family

Joan Maurice married fellow economist Austin Robinson in 1926.[14] The marriage produced two recorded daughters.[14]

The distinguished London surgeon and Cambridge academic Howard Marsh was Joan Robinson's maternal grandfather.

Recognition

In 2016 the Council of the University of Cambridge approved the use of Robinson's name to mark a physical feature within the North West Cambridge Development.[15]

Major works

  • The Economics of Imperfect Competition (1933)
  • An Essay on Marxian Economics (1942), Second Edition (1966) (The Macmillan Press Ltd, ISBN 0-333-05800-3)
  • The Production Function and the Theory of Capital (1953)
  • Accumulation of Capital (1956)
  • Exercises in Economic Analysis (1960)
  • Essays in the Theory of Economic Growth (1962)
  • Economic Philosophy: An Essay on the Progress of Economic Thought (1962)
  • Freedom and Necessity: An Introduction to the Study of Society (1970)
  • Economic Heresies: Some Old Fashioned Questions in Economic Theory (1971) (Basic Books, New York, ISBN 0-465-01786-X)
  • Contributions to Modern Economics (1978) (Basil Blackwell, Oxford, ISBN 0-631-19220-4)

Texts for the lay reader

  • Economics is a serious subject: The apologia of an economist to the mathematician, the scientist and the plain man (1932), W. Heffer & Sons
  • Introduction to the Theory of Employment (1937)
  • The Cultural Revolution in China, Harmondsworth: Pelican Original (1969)
  • An Introduction to Modern Economics (1973) with John Eatwell
  • The Arms Race (1981), Tanner Lectures on Human Values

See also

References

  1. Register of Marriages for St George's, Hanover Square, January–March 1899, volume 1a, p. 618
  2. "Joan Robinson". spartacus-educational.com. Archived from the original on 11 November 2017. Retrieved 27 April 2018.
  3. Phillip Knightley, Philby: KGB Masterspy (1988), p. 30
  4. Joan Robinson, interviewed by Andrew Boyle for his book The Climate of Treason (1979), page 47
  5. Joseph Persky and Herbert Tsang (February 1974). "Pigouvian Exploitation of Labor". The Review of Economics and Statistics. JSTOR 1927526.
  6. "Notes on Monopsony Model of Gender Wage Gaps" (PDF). Archived (PDF) from the original on 3 February 2014. Retrieved 1 February 2014.
  7. Stephen Wilks, In the Public Interest: Competition Policy and the Monopolies and Mergers Commission, p. 93
  8. "Book of Members, 1780–2010: Chapter R" (PDF). American Academy of Arts and Sciences. Archived (PDF) from the original on 13 June 2011. Retrieved 22 July 2014.
  9. Stiglitz, Joseph E. "Autobiography" Archived 31 May 2013 at the Wayback Machine., Nobel Foundation, Stockholm, December 2002. Retrieved on 8 May 2012.
  10. Sen, Amartya "Autobiography" Archived 16 June 2013 at the Wayback Machine., Nobel Foundation, Stockholm, 1998. Retrieved on 8 May 2012.
  11. Heonik Kwon; Byung-Ho Chung (12 March 2012). North Korea: Beyond Charismatic Politics. Rowman & Littlefield Publishers. pp. 151–152. ISBN 978-1-4422-1577-1.
  12. Harcourt, Geoffrey Colin (2006). The Structure of Post-Keynesian Economics. Cambridge University Press. p. 92. ISBN 9780765637017. Retrieved 31 December 2010.
  13. Harcourt, p. 169.
  14. 1 2 Who's who 1958. London: Adam & Charles Black limited. 1958.
  15. Administrator (29 January 2015). "Street Naming". www.nwcambridge.co.uk. Archived from the original on 9 March 2017. Retrieved 8 March 2017.

Further reading

  • Emani, Zohreh, 2000, "Joan Robinson" in Robert W. Dimand et al. (eds), A Biographical Dictionary of Women Economists, Edward Elgar.
  • Harcourt, G. C., 1995, Obituary: Joan Robinson 1903–1983, Economic Journal, Vol. 105, No. 432. (September 1995), pp. 1228–1243.
  • Harcourt, G. C. and Kerr, P. (2009). Joan Robinson. Palgrave MacMillan.
  • Pasinetti, Luigi L. (1987), "Robinson, Joan Violet," The New Palgrave: A Dictionary of Economics, v. 4, pp. 212–17, Macmillan.
  • Vianello, F. [1996], "Joan Robinson on Normal Prices (and the Normal rate of Profits)", in: Marcuzzo, M.C. and Pasinetti, L. and Roncaglia, A. (eds.), The Economics of Joan Robinson, New York: Routledge, ISBN 978-0415136167.
  • Joan Violet Robinson, 1903–1983 The New School
  • Joan Robinson at Stanford, May 1974 Australian School of Business, 27 March 2009 – Three hours of Robinson' lectures at Stanford, 1974
  • Life and economics of Joan Robinson Life and economics of Joan Robinson
  • Joan Violet Robinson (1903–1983). The Concise Encyclopedia of Economics. Library of Economics and Liberty (2nd ed.). Liberty Fund. 2008.
  • Works by Joan Robinson at Project Gutenberg
This article is issued from Wikipedia. The text is licensed under Creative Commons - Attribution - Sharealike. Additional terms may apply for the media files.