Gunnar Myrdal

Karl Gunnar Myrdal (/ˈmɜːrdɑːl, ˈmɪər-/ MUR-dahl, MEER-, Swedish: [ˈɡɵ̌nːar ˈmy̌ːɖɑːl]; 6 December 1898 – 17 May 1987) was a Swedish economist and sociologist. In 1974, he received the Nobel Memorial Prize in Economic Sciences with Friedrich Hayek for "their pioneering work in the theory of money and economic fluctuations and for their penetrating analysis of the interdependence of economic, social and institutional phenomena."[1] He is best known in the United States for his study of race relations, which culminated in his book An American Dilemma: The Negro Problem and Modern Democracy. The study was influential in the 1954 landmark U.S. Supreme Court Decision Brown v. Board of Education. In Sweden, his work and political influence were important to the establishment of the Folkhemmet and the welfare state.

Gunnar Myrdal
Gunnar Myrdal in January 1964
Born
Karl Gunnar Myrdal

(1898-12-06)6 December 1898
Skattungbyn, Orsa Municipality, Sweden
Died17 May 1987(1987-05-17) (aged 88)
Trångsund, Sweden
NationalitySwedish
Alma materStockholm University
Known forMonetary equilibrium,

Ex-ante,

Circular cumulative causation
Spouse(s)
Alva Myrdal
(m. 1924; died 1986)
AwardsNobel Memorial Prize in Economic Sciences (1974)[1]
Bronislaw Malinowski Award (1975)
Scientific career
FieldsEconomics, Politics, Sociology
InstitutionsNYU, Stockholm University
Doctoral advisorGustav Cassel
Doctoral students
  • Rudolf Meidner
  • Leo Törnqvist
InfluencesKnut Wicksell
John R. Commons[2]
Raúl Prebisch
InfluencedHa-Joon Chang
G. L. S. Shackle

Early life and education

Myrdal was born on 6 December 1898, in Skattungbyn, Sweden, to Karl Adolf Pettersson (1876–1934), a building contractor, and his wife Anna Sofia Karlsson (1878–1965). He took the name Myrdal in 1914 after his ancestors' farm Myr in the province of Dalarna.

There is a possibly apocryphal story about an interaction between him and Gustav Cassel, where Cassel was reported to say, "Gunnar, you should be more respectful to your elders, because it is we who will determine your promotion," and he replied, "Yes, but it is we who will write your obituaries."[3]

Gunnar Myrdal graduated with a law degree from Stockholm University in 1923 and a doctorate in economics in 1927. In June 1919, he met Alva Reimer, whom he married in October 1924[4] and had the first of their three children in 1927.

Myrdal's PhD thesis, The Problem of Price Formation under Economic Change, had three parts: The Basics of the Dynamic Problem of Price Formation, The Problem of the Profit of the Enterprise, and The Optimal Mode of Construction and Change, the most mathematical of the three, where he studied equilibrium of price formation under dynamic conditions.

In Gunnar Myrdal's doctoral dissertation, published in 1927, he examined the role of expectations in price formation. His analysis strongly influenced the Stockholm school. He built on Knut Wicksell's theories of cumulative process of endogenous money, stressing the importance of Knightian uncertainty and Ex ante and Ex post expectations role in the economic process.

Early career

Between 1925 and 1929, Myrdal studied in Britain and Germany. He was a Rockefeller Fellow and visited the United States in 1929–1930. During this period he published his first books, including The Political Element in the Development of Economic Theory in 1930. Returning to Europe, he served for one year as associate professor in the Graduate Institute of International Studies, Geneva, Switzerland.[5]

The Political Element is a compilation of Myrdal's lectures presented at the University of Stockholm. It gives us the historical account of the influence of politics in the development of economic theory and the relation between them. Gunnar believed that economics would be considered a true science only when the political aspect was dissociated. It was initially written to criticize the older generation of Swedish economists such as Eli Heckscher, Gustav Cassel, and Brisman, for combining and confusing facts and values in their theories of ‘maximum welfare’, ‘price level’, and ‘national income’. But later it turned out be a general critique of the economic theory where he emphasized that economics should be objective and independent from values. He wrote that although economists claim to be scientific and objective, their conclusion from their analyses was always politically inclined. The Political Element was translated to German in 1932 and to English in 1953.[6]

Gunnar Myrdal was at first fascinated by the abstract mathematical models coming into fashion in the 1920s, and helped found the Econometric Society in London. Later, however, he accused the movement of ignoring the problem of distribution of wealth in its obsession with economic growth, of using faulty statistics and substituting Greek letters for missing data in its formulas and of flouting logic. He wrote, "Correlations are not explanations and besides, they can be as spurious as the high correlation in Finland between foxes killed and divorces." Professor Myrdal was an early supporter of the theses of John Maynard Keynes, although he maintained that the basic idea of adjusting national budgets to slow or speed an economy was first developed by him and articulated in his book Monetary Economics, published in 1932, four years prior to Keynes' General Theory of Employment, Interest and Money.[3]

William Barber's comment upon Myrdal's work on monetary theory goes like this:

If his contribution had been available to readers of English before 1936, it is interesting to speculate whether the ‘revolution’ in macroeconomic theory of the depression decade would be referred to as 'Myrdalian' as much as 'Keynesian'.[7]

Economist G. L. S. Shackle claimed the importance of Gunnar Myrdal's analysis by which saving and investment are allowed to adjust ex ante to each other. However, the reference to ex ante and ex post analysis has become so usual in modern macroeconomics that the position of Keynes to not include it in his work was currently considered as an oddity, if not a mistake. As Shackle put it:

Myrdalian ex ante language would have saved the General Theory from describing the flow of investment and the flow of saving as identically, tautologically equal, and within the same discourse, treating their equality as a condition which may, or not, be fulfilled.[8]

Gunnar Myrdal also developed the key concept circular cumulative causation, a multi-causal approach where the core variables and their linkages are delineated.

Academic career

Gunnar Myrdal became professor at Stockholms Högskola 1933.[9] Myrdal was professor of economics at Stockholms Högskola for 15 years, until 1947.[9]

He became a Social Democratic Member of Parliament from 1933 and from 1945 to 1947 he served as Trade Minister in Tage Erlander's government. During this period he was heavily criticised for his financial agreement with the Soviet Union. At the same time he was accused of being responsible for the Swedish monetary crisis in 1947.[10]

He coauthored with his wife, Alva Myrdal, the Crisis in the Population Question (Swedish: Kris i befolkningsfrågan, 1934). The work of Gunnar and Alva inspired policies adopted by the Minister of Social Affairs, Gustav Möller, to provide social support to families.

Gunnar Myrdal headed a comprehensive study of sociological, economic, anthropological and legal data on race relations in the United States funded by the Carnegie Corporation, starting in 1938. The result of the effort was Gunnar Myrdal's best-known work, An American Dilemma: The Negro Problem and Modern Democracy, published in 1944, written with the collaboration of R. M. E. Sterner and Arnold Rose.[11] He characterized the problem of race relations as a dilemma because of a perceived conflict between high ideals, embodied in what he called the "American Creed," on the one hand and poor performance on the other. In the generations since the Civil War, the U.S. had been unable to put its human rights ideals into practice for the African-American tenth of its population.[12] This book was cited by the U.S. Supreme Court in its 1954 decision in Brown v. Board of Education, which outlawed racial segregation in public schools. Myrdal planned on doing a similar study on gender inequality, but he could not find funding for this project and never completed it.

World War II and after

During World War II, Gunnar Myrdal was staunchly and publicly anti-Nazi. Together with his wife, Alva, he wrote Contact with America in 1941, which praised the United States' democratic institutions.[13]

Gunnar Myrdal became the Executive Secretary of the United Nations Economic Commission for Europe in 1947. During his tenure, he founded one of the leading centers of economic research and policy development.[14] After ten years in the position, Dr. Myrdal resigned as Executive Secretary in 1957. In 1956 and 1957, he was able to publish An International Economy, Problems and Prospects, Rich Lands and Poor and Economic Theory and Underdeveloped Regions. Myrdal was also a signatory of the 1950 UNESCO statement The Race Question, which rebuts the theories of racial supremacy and purity, and also influenced the Brown v. Board of Education decision. In 1956, Myrdal wrote the foreword for African American author Richard Wright's The Color Curtain: A Report on the Bandung Conference.

Between 1960 and 1967, he was a professor of international economics at Stockholm University. In 1961, he founded the Institute for International Economic Studies at the University. Throughout the 1960s, he worked on a comprehensive study of trends and policies in South Asia for the Twentieth Century Fund. The study culminated in his three-volume Asian Drama: An Inquiry into the Poverty of Nations, published in 1968. In 1970, he published a companion book called The Challenge of World Poverty, where he laid out what he believed to be the chief policy solutions to the problems he outlined in Asian Drama.

Gunnar Myrdal strongly opposed the Vietnam War. In Asian Drama, Myrdal predicted that land reform and pacification would fail in Vietnam and urged the United States to begin negotiations with North Vietnam. After returning to Sweden, he headed the Swedish Vietnam Committee and became co-chair of International Commission of Inquiry Into U.S. War Crimes in Indochina. He also presided over the Stockholm International Peace Research Institute, an international watch-dog for the arms trade.[15] He was one of the signers of the Humanist Manifesto.[16]

In 1967 Myrdal received an honorary doctorate from Sir George Williams University, which later became Concordia University.[17]

In 1971 both he and his wife received honorary doctorates from Gustavus Adolphus College in Saint Peter, Minnesota.

He shared the Bank of Sweden Prize in Economic Sciences (otherwise known as the Nobel Memorial Prize in Economics) with Friedrich Hayek in 1974,[18] but argued for its abolition because it had been given to such "reactionaries" as Hayek and Milton Friedman.

During 19741975, he served as visiting professor at NYU.[19]

Myrdal received an Honorary Doctorate from Heriot-Watt University in 1979.[20]

Personal life

Myrdal was married to politician and diplomat Alva Myrdal in 1924, and together had two daughters, Kaj Fölster (mother of Swedish economist Stefan Fölster) and Sissela Bok, and a son, Jan Myrdal. Alva Myrdal was a prominent leader of the disarmament movement. She, along with Alfonso Garcia Robles, received the Nobel Peace Prize in 1982.

Myrdal suffered from Parkinson's disease and was hospitalized for two months before he died in a hospital in Trångsund, south of Stockholm, on 17 May 1987. His daughter Kaj Fölster and his grandson, Janken Myrdal, were present.[21]

Contributions to the philosophy of knowledge

Gunnar Myrdal's scientific influence was not limited to economics. Through the introduction to Asian Drama with the title "The Beam in our Eyes" (a biblical reference; cf. Matthew 7:1–2) he introduced the approach mentioned as scientific relativism of values. This behavioral approach is narrowly connected to behavioralism and is built on the idea that the logical gulf between "is" and "ought" is more sophisticated than just dividing premises into categories. The articles edited in "Value in Social Theory" underlines Myrdal's importance to political science. As political science normally is considered more descriptive than economics, one might get the idea that Myrdal should not have dealt systematically with the values applied to economics. On the contrary, Myrdal connected social science, political science and economics as a practitioner.

Myrdal published many notable works, both before and after American Dilemma and, among many other contributions to social and public policy, founded and chaired the Stockholm International Peace Research Institute. Internationally revered as a father-figure of social policy, he contributed to social democratic thinking throughout the world, in collaboration with friends and colleagues in the political and academic arenas. Sweden and Britain were among the pioneers of a welfare state and books by Myrdal (Beyond the Welfare State – New Haven, 1958) and Richard Titmuss (Essays on “The Welfare State” – London, 1958) unsurprisingly explore similar themes. Myrdal's theoretical key concept "circular cumulative causation" contributed to the development of modern Non-equilibrium economics.[22]

Welfare World

The welfare world enable to redistribute a welfare not only in a country but also in the whole world. At the Cold War time, In Beyond the welfare state he wrote, he proposed idea of welfare world to break the limitation of the West welfare state. However, he also thought it is more difficult to establish the welfare world than a welfare state.[23]

He pointed out the following limitations of the welfare state:

  • Nationalism of already existing Western welfare states preventing development in underdeveloped countries.
  • Other difficulties of development in the developing countries.
  • Existence of the communist countries acting as a provocateur for more revolutionary transformations.

Publications

  • The Political Element in the Development of Economic Theory. (1930)
  • Monetary Equilibrium (1931), translated to English in 1939
  • The Cost of Living in Sweden, 1830–1930 (1933)
  • Crisis in the Population Question (1934)
  • Fiscal Policy in the Business Cycle. The American Economic Review, vol 21, no 1, Mar 1939.
  • Population, a Problem for Democracy. Harvard University Press, 1940.
  • Contact With America (1941)[24]
  • An American Dilemma: The Negro Problem and Modern Democracy. Harper & Bros, 1944.
  • Social Trends in America and Strategic Approaches to the Negro Problem. Phylon, Vol. 9, No. 3, 3rd Quarter, 1948.
  • Conference of the British Sociological Association, 1953. II Opening Address: The Relation between Social Theory and Social Policy The British Journal of Sociology, Vol. 4, No. 3, Sept. 1953.
  • An International Economy, Problems and Prospects. Harper & Brothers Publishers, 1956.
  • Rich Lands and Poor. 1957.
  • Economic Theory and Underdeveloped Regions, Gerald Duckworth, 1957.
  • Value in Social Theory: A Selection of Essays on Methodology. Ed. Paul Streeten, published by Harper, 1958.
  • Myrdal (1960). Beyond the Welfare State. Yale University Press.CS1 maint: ref=harv (link)
  • Challenge to Affluence. Random House, 1963.
  • America and Vietnam – Transition, No. 3, Oct, 1967.
  • Twenty Years of the United Nations Economic Commission for Europe. International Organization, Vol 22, No. 3, Summer, 1968.
  • Asian Drama: An Inquiry into the Poverty of Nations, 1968.
  • Objectivity in Social Research, 1969.
  • The Challenge of World Poverty: A World Anti-Poverty Program in Outline. 1970.
  • Against the Stream.
  • Hur Styrs Landet?, 1982.
  • Gunnar Myrdal on Population Policy in the Underdeveloped World – Population and Development Review, Vol 13, No. 3, Sept. 1987.
  • The Equality Issue in World Development – The American Economic Review, vol 79, no 6, Dec 1989.

References

  1. "The Sveriges Riksbank Prize in Economic Sciences in Memory of Alfred Nobel 1974". NobelPrize.org. Retrieved 2009-11-27.
  2. Jackson, Walter A. (1994-02-01). Gunnar Myrdal and America's Conscience: Social Engineering and Racial Liberalism, 1938-1987. UNC Press Books. ISBN 978-0-8078-4460-1.
  3. "Gunnar Myrdal, Analyst of Race Crisis, Dies". The New York Times. 1987-05-18. Retrieved 2010-08-17.
  4. "(Karl) Gunnar Mydral Biography". biography.com. August 9, 2010. Archived from the original on August 18, 2010. Retrieved 2010-08-09.
  5. "Biography". nobelprize.org. August 9, 2010. Retrieved 2010-08-09.
  6. Myrdal, Gunnar (2017). The Political Element in the Development of Economic Theory with a new introduction by Richard Swedberg. 2 Park Square, Milton Park, Abingdon, Oxon OX14 4RN 711 Third Avenue, New York, NY 10017, USA: Routledge, Taylor and Francis Group. pp. xvi–xvii, xxiii. ISBN 978-0-88738-827-9.CS1 maint: location (link)
  7. Barber, William (2008). Gunnar Myrdal : an intellectual biography. Basingstoke: Palgrave Macmillan. ISBN 978-0-230-28901-7. OCLC 681925215.
  8. Shackle, G.L.S. (1989). "3: What did the General Theory do?". In John Pheby (ed.). New Directions in Post-Keynesian Economics. Edward Elgar Publishing. p. 48. ISBN 978-1-78254-355-8.
  9. "Gunnar Myrdal - Uppslagsverk - NE.se". www.ne.se.
  10. Appelqvist, Örjan (1999-06-15), Gunnar Myrdal i svensk politik 1943–1947, Humboldt-Universität zu Berlin, doi:10.18452/7729, retrieved 2019-08-14
  11. "Gunnar Myrdal Facts, information, pictures". Encyclopedia.com. August 11, 2010. Retrieved 2010-08-11.
  12. "An American Dilemma". PBS.org. August 9, 2010. Retrieved 2010-08-09.
  13. "Gunnar Myrdal, Analyst of Race Crisis, Dies". The New York Times. Retrieved 2010-08-17.
  14. "Gunnar Myrdal, An Intellectual Biography". Epress.anu.edu.au. August 11, 2010. Archived from the original on 2011-04-11. Retrieved 2010-08-11.
  15. "Gunnar Myrdal, Analyst of Race Crisis, Dies". The New York Times. 1987-05-18. ISSN 0362-4331. Retrieved 2019-08-14.
  16. "Humanist Manifesto II". American Humanist Association. Retrieved October 10, 2012.
  17. "Honorary Degree Citation - Karl Gunnar Myrdal* | Concordia University Archives". archives.concordia.ca. Retrieved 2016-03-29.
  18. "The Prize in Economics 1974". nobelprize.org. August 9, 2010. Retrieved 2010-08-09.
  19. Clark, Kenneth Bancroft (2004). Toward Humanity and Justice: The Writings of Kenneth B. Clark, Scholar of the 1954 Brown V. Board of Education Decision. Greenwood Publishing Group. p. 285. ISBN 978-0-275-97509-8.
  20. webperson@hw.ac.uk. "Heriot-Watt University Edinburgh: Honorary Graduates". www1.hw.ac.uk. Retrieved 2016-04-06.
  21. "Gunnar Myrdal, Analyst of Race Crisis, Dies". The New York Times. 1987-05-18. Retrieved 2010-08-17.
  22. Berger, Sebastian (July 6, 2009). The Foundations of Non-Equilibrium Economics. The principle of circular and cumulative causation. Routledge. ISBN 978-0-415-77780-3. Retrieved 21 October 2010.
  23. Myrdal (1960), p. 220 (by the Japanese ed.).
  24. Roberts, Gene; Klibanoff, Hank (2007). The Race Beat: The Press, the Civil Rights Struggle, and the Awakening of a Nation. Vintage. ISBN 978-0-679-73565-6.
Awards
Preceded by
Wassily Leontief
Laureate of the Nobel Memorial Prize in Economics
1974
Served alongside: Friedrich August von Hayek
Succeeded by
Leonid Vitaliyevich Kantorovich
Tjalling C. Koopmans
This article is issued from Wikipedia. The text is licensed under Creative Commons - Attribution - Sharealike. Additional terms may apply for the media files.