Structural estimation

Structural estimation is a technique for estimating deep "structural" parameters of theoretical economic models. The term is inherited from the simultaneous equations model. In this sense "structural estimation" is contrasted with "reduced-form estimation", which is the statistical relationship between observed variables.[1]

The difference between a structural parameter and a reduced-form parameter was formalized in the work of the Cowles Foundation.[1] A structural parameter is also said to be "policy invariant" whereas the value of reduced-form parameter can depend on exogenously determined parameters set by public policy makers. The distinction between structural and reduced-form estimation within "microeconometrics" is related to the Lucas critique of reduced-form macroeconomic policy predictions.

The original distinction between structure and reduced-form was between the underlying system and the direct relationship between observables implied by the system. Different combinations of structural parameters can imply the same reduced-form parameters, so structural estimation must go beyond the direct relationship between variables.[1][2]

Many economists now use the term "reduced form" to mean statistical estimation without reference to a specific economic model. For example, a regression is often called a reduced-form equation even when no standard economic model would generate it as the reduced form relationship between variables.

These conflicting distinctions between structural and reduced form estimation arose from the increasing complexity of economic theory since the formalization of simultaneous equations estimation. A structural model often involves sequential decision-making under uncertainty or strategic environments where beliefs about other agents' actions matter. Parameters of such models are estimated not with regression analysis but non-linear techniques such as generalized method of moments, maximum likelihood, and indirect inference. The reduced-form of such models may result in a regression relationship but often only for special or trivial cases of the structural parameters.

See also

Notes

References

  • Angrist, Joshua D; Pischke, Jörn-Steffen (2010). "The Credibility Revolution in Empirical Economics: How Better Research Design is Taking the Con out of Econometrics" (PDF). Journal of Economic Perspectives. American Economic Association. 24 (2): 3–30. doi:10.1257/jep.24.2.3. ISSN 0895-3309.CS1 maint: ref=harv (link)
  • Keane, Michael P. (2010). "Structural vs. atheoretic approaches to econometrics". Journal of Econometrics. Elsevier BV. 156 (1): 3–20. doi:10.1016/j.jeconom.2009.09.003. ISSN 0304-4076.CS1 maint: ref=harv (link)
  • Reiss, Peter C.; Wolak, Frank A. (2007). "Chapter 64 Structural Econometric Modeling: Rationales and Examples from Industrial Organization". Handbook of Econometrics. Elsevier. doi:10.1016/s1573-4412(07)06064-3. ISBN 978-0-444-50631-3. ISSN 1573-4412.CS1 maint: ref=harv (link)
  • Rust, John (2014). "The Limits of Inference with Theory: A Review of Wolpin (2013)". Journal of Economic Literature. American Economic Association. 52 (3): 820–850. doi:10.1257/jel.52.3.820. ISSN 0022-0515.CS1 maint: ref=harv (link)
This article is issued from Wikipedia. The text is licensed under Creative Commons - Attribution - Sharealike. Additional terms may apply for the media files.