Social preferences

Social preferences are a type of preferences studied in behavioral and experimental economics and social psychology. A person exhibits social preferences if he/she not only cares about his/her own material payoff, but also the reference group's payoff or/and the intention that leads to the payoff.[1] Types of social preferences include altruism, fairness, reciprocity, and inequity aversion.[2]

The field of economics was predicated on humans being rational economic actors, and as it became apparent that this was never true, the entire field went into a crisis from which it has yet to recover. The research of social preferences in economics started with lab experiments in 1980, where experimental economists found subjects' behavior deviated systematically from self-interest behavior in economic games such as ultimatum game and dictator game. These experimental findings then inspired various new economic models to characterize agent's altruism, fairness and reciprocity concern between 1990 and 2010. More recently, there are growing amounts of field experiments that study the shaping of social preference and its applications in the workplace and other economic settings.[1]

Formation of social preferences

Biologists, social psychologists, and economists have proposed theories and documented evidence on the formation of social preferences over both the long run and the short run.[3]

Biological evolution

Kin selection

Kin selection is an evolutionary strategy where some specific behavioral traits are favored to benefit close relatives' reproduction.[4] Hence, behavior that appears altruistic can align with the theory of the selfish gene.[5] Kin selection can explain altruistic behavior towards close relatives even at the cost of their own's survival, as long as one's sacrifice can help preserve a greater amount of the same genes in close relatives.[6] For example, worker bees can die from attacking their predators in order to help preserve other bees' genes.[3]

Reciprocity selection

Reciprocity selection suggests that one's altruistic act may evolve from the anticipation of future reciprocal altruistic behavior from others.[7] An application of reciprocity selection in game theory is the Tit-For-Tat strategy in prisoner's dilemma, which is the strategy that the player cooperate at the initial encounter, and then follow the opponent's behavior on the previous encounter.[8] Robert Axelrod and W. D. Hamilton showed that Tit-For-Tat strategy can be an evolutionary stable strategy in a population where the probability of repeated encounters between two persons in a population is above a certain threshold.[9]

Social learning

Psychologist Albert Bandura proposed that children learn about pro-social and moral behavior by imitating other pro-social models, including parents, other adults, and peers. There are also economic models proposing that parents transmit their social preferences to their children by demonstrating their own pro-social behavior.[10][11]

However, empirical support for parents' role in fostering pro-social behavior is mixed.[12] For example, some researchers found a positive relation between the parent's use of induction and children's pro-social behavior,[13] and others found no correlation between parent's adoption of punitive techniques and children's pro-social behavior.[3]

Regarding other sources of social learning, recent field experiments have provided causal evidences for positive effects of school program and mentoring program on forming social preferences,[14][15] and these research suggested that social interaction, prosocial role models[14] as well as cultural transmission from family and school[15] are potential mechanisms.

Cognitive factors

Psychologist Jean Piaget was among the first to propose that cognitive development is a pre-requisite in moral judgment and behavior. He argued for the importance of social interaction with others rather than learning in moral development, which requires the understanding of both rules and others' behavior. Other important cognitive skills in fostering pro-social behavior include perspective taking and moral reasoning,[16][17] which are supported by most empirical evidence.[18][19]

Evidences of social preferences

Experimental evidences

Many initial evidences of social preferences came from lab experiments where subjects play economic games with others. However, many research found that subjects' behavior robustly and systematically deviated from the prediction from self-interest hypothesis, but could be explained by social preferences including altruism, inequity aversion and reciprocity.[1]

Ultimatum game is one of the first experiments that shows self-interest hypothesis fails to predict people's behavior. In this game, the first mover proposes a split of a fixed amount, and the second mover decides to accept or reject the offer. If the second mover accepts the offer, the final payoff is exactly determined by the offer. However, if the second mover rejects the offer, both subjects will have zero payoff.[20] Contrary to the self-interest hypothesis's prediction that the first mover will propose zero amount and the second mover will accept the offer, experimenters found proposers will typically offer 25%-50% of the fixed amount, and responders tend to reject the offer when the split is below 20%.[21]

A relevant game is dictator game, where one subject proposes the split of a fixed amount and the other subject is only allowed to accept the offer. The dictator game helps to isolate pure altruism from the strategic concern of the first mover (i.e. the first mover proposes a larger share to second mover to avoid second mover's rejection) in the ultimatum game.[22] In this game, the average share decreases to 20% of the fixed amount, however, more than 60% of the subjects still propose a positive offer.[21]

Two other games, trust game (also called investment game) and gift-exchange game provide evidence for reciprocal behavior. In the trust game, the first mover is endowed with a fixed amount c, and decides the amount of money b to pass on to the second mover. This amount is multiplied by a factor of k when it reaches the second mover, and then the second mover decides how much of this amount (kb) is returned to the first mover.[23] While self-interest model predicts no transfer and no return, experimenters found that first mover typically transfers roughly 50% of endowment and responder's return increases with the transfer.[21] In gift exchange game, the first mover proposes some offer to the second mover and asks for certain effort level from the second mover, and then the second mover decides his/her effort that is costly but can increase first mover's payoff.[24] Also contrary to the self-interest prediction, first mover's offer in experiments is usually greater than zero, and the second mover's effort level increases with offer.[21]

Prisoner's dilemma and its generalized game, public goods game also provide indirect evidence for social preference, and there are many evidences of conditional cooperation among subjects.[25]

Field evidences

Many field evidences documented agent's fairness and reciprocal concern. For example, Daniel Kahneman, Jack Knetsch and Richard Thaler found that the concern for fairness constrains firm's profit seeking behavior (e.g. raise price after an increase in demand).[26] There are also evidences that perceived fairness of the tax system and law affects tax compliance and law enforcement.[27][28]

Many field experiments examine relative pay concerns and reciprocity in work settings. For example, economists Uri Gneezy and John List conducted field experiments where subjects were hired for a typing job and for door-to-door fundraising and found subjects exerted larger effort level in group with a higher wage.[29] However, this positive reciprocity was short lived.[29] Researchers have also found that positive reciprocity is smaller than negative reciprocity. In another study,[30] job applicants were hired to catalog books for 6 hours with a pronounced wage, but applicants were later informed with either wage increase or wage cut. Researchers found the decrease in effort in wage cut group was larger than the increase in effort in wage increase group. However, positive reciprocity did not extend to other activities (volunteering to work for one more hour).[30] One study also documented decrease in worker's effort when workers experienced wage cuts, but this effort level change was affected by the perceived justification for wage cuts.[31]

Economic models of social preferences

Existing models of social preferences can be divided into two types: distributive preferences and reciprocal preferences. Distributive preferences are the preferences over the distribution and total magnitude of the payoff among the reference groups, including altruism and spitefulness, fairness and inequity aversion, and efficiency concern; while reciprocal preferences reflect agent's concern over the intention of other's behavior and agent's motivation to reciprocate positively or negatively depending on the kindness and fairness of other's behavior.[32]

Pure altruism, warm glow, and spitefulness

Pure altruism in economic models represents an agent's concern on other's well-being. A person exhibits altruistic preference if this person's utility increases with other's payoff.[33][34] A related economic model is impure altruism, or warm-glow, where individuals feel good (i.e. gain a "warm-glow" utility) from doing something good without caring about other's payoff.[35]

Spitefulness or envy preference is the opposite of pure altruism, where an agent's utility decreases with other's payoff.[33][34]

Fairness and inequity aversion

Fairness and inequity aversion models capture the agent's concern on the fair distribution of payoffs across agents and especially the aversion to payoff differences.[36]

In the Fehr-Schmidt model,[36] an agent compares his payoff to each other opponents in the group. However, the agent's utility decreases with both positive and negative payoff differences between self and each other opponent in the reference group. Moreover, the agent dislikes payoff disadvantage more than payoff advantage. Hence, the agent presents altruistic behavior towards others when agent is better off than others, and displays spiteful behavior when agent is worse off than others.[36]

In a related model by Bolton and Ockenfels (1999), inequity aversion is modeled with a more general functional form, where agent also cares about fair share but is only concerned about the average payoff of the reference group, rather than each individual's payoff in the reference group.[37]

Efficiency concern and quasi-maximin preferences

Economists Gary Charness and Matthew Rabin found that in some cases, agents prefer more efficient outcomes (i.e. outcome with larger social welfare) than more equal outcomes[38] and they developed a model where agents' utility is a convex combination of own's material payoff and the social welfare. Moreover, they assumed agents have quasi-maximin preferences, meaning that agents' care on social welfare includes the minimum payoff among agents as well as the total payoff for all agents in the group. However, the agent will care less about others' payoff if other is better off than self.[38]

Reciprocity

Agent has the motivation to reciprocate towards both kind and unfair behavior. Rabin (1993)'s model is one of the earliest model that characterizes reciprocal behavior. In this model, the agent's payoff depends on the other opponent, and agent forms belief of the other opponent's kindness, which is based on the difference between the actual payoff that agent receives and the fair payoff. Agents will reciprocate positively if he/she perceives the other individual's behavior as kind and fair and respond negatively if he/she perceives it as unfair.[39]

Other researchers further generalize Rabin (1993)'s model by studying repeated interactions in N-person extensive form games,[40] and also by including inequity aversion into agent's preference.[41] Charness and Rabin also augmented their quasi-maximin preference with reciprocity concern.[38] However, this type of reciprocity models usually has multiple equilibria and suffers from model complexity, which makes it hard to empirically test for the model.

Economic applications

Researchers have argued that the failure of recognizing social preference will lead to a biased understanding of much important economic behavior.[42]

Understanding cooperation

Research on social preferences showed that reciprocal and inequity averse individuals can cooperate if they are sure that others will cooperate too and can punish the free riders. This has implications for designing proper social mechanisms to solve the free-riding problem.[33]

Design of economic incentive

Accounting employee's reciprocity and fairness concerns can help design better contracts (e.g. trust contract, bonus contract) to enhance employee's effort and to solve firm's agency problems. Moreover, the design of relative pay in the workplace can affect employee's job satisfaction and well-being.[31][43] Research on social preference has also facilitated the understanding of monetary incentives' crowding-out effect.[44]

Design of social policies

Accounting individual's fairness concerns can affect the design of the social policies, especially for redistributive policies. In addition, reciprocal preferences can affect people's evaluation of different policies towards the poor depending on the individual's belief that whether the poor are deserving or undeserving.[45]

See also

References

  1. Carpenter, Jeffrey (2008). "Social Preferences". The New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics. pp. 1–5. doi:10.1057/978-1-349-95121-5_1974-1. ISBN 978-1-349-95121-5.
  2. behavioralecon. "Social preferences". behavioraleconomics.com | The BE Hub. Retrieved 2019-11-25.
  3. Lévy-Garboua, Louis; Meidinger, Claude; Rapoport, Benoît (2006-01-01), "Chapter 7 The Formation of Social Preferences: Some Lessons from Psychology and Biology", in Kolm, Serge-Christophe; Ythier, Jean Mercier (eds.), Handbook of the Economics of Giving, Altruism and Reciprocity, Foundations, 1, Elsevier, pp. 545–613, doi:10.1016/s1574-0714(06)01007-4, ISBN 9780444506979
  4. Smith, J. Maynard (March 1964). "Group Selection and Kin Selection". Nature. 201 (4924): 1145–1147. Bibcode:1964Natur.201.1145S. doi:10.1038/2011145a0. ISSN 0028-0836.
  5. Dawkins, Richard (1976). The Selfish Gene. Oxford University Press, Oxford.
  6. Hamilton, W. D. (2017-07-12), "The Genetical Evolution of Social Behavior. I.", Group Selection, Routledge, pp. 23–43, doi:10.4324/9780203790427-4, ISBN 978-0-203-79042-7
  7. Trivers, Robert L. (1971-03-01). "The Evolution of Reciprocal Altruism". The Quarterly Review of Biology. 46 (1): 35–57. doi:10.1086/406755. ISSN 0033-5770.
  8. Axelrod, Robert (March 1980). "Effective Choice in the Prisoner's Dilemma". Journal of Conflict Resolution. 24 (1): 3–25. doi:10.1177/002200278002400101. ISSN 0022-0027.
  9. Axelrod, R; Hamilton, W. (1981-03-27). "The evolution of cooperation". Science. 211 (4489): 1390–1396. Bibcode:1981Sci...211.1390A. doi:10.1126/science.7466396. ISSN 0036-8075. PMID 7466396.
  10. Bisin, Alberto; Verdier, Thierry (2001-04-01). "The Economics of Cultural Transmission and the Dynamics of Preferences". Journal of Economic Theory. 97 (2): 298–319. doi:10.1006/jeth.2000.2678. ISSN 0022-0531.
  11. Cox, Donald; Stark, Oded (2007). "On the Demand for Grandchildren: Tied Transfers and the Demonstration Effect" (PDF). Handbook on the Economics of Happiness. doi:10.4337/9781847204158.00026. ISBN 9781847204158.
  12. Arrondel, Luc; Masson, Andre (2001). "Family Transfers Involving Three Generations". The Scandinavian Journal of Economics. 103 (3): 415–443. doi:10.1111/1467-9442.00253. ISSN 1467-9442.
  13. Eisenberg, Nancy; Fabes, Richard A.; Spinrad, Tracy L. (2007-06-01), "Prosocial Development", Handbook of Child Psychology, John Wiley & Sons, Inc., doi:10.1002/9780470147658.chpsy0311, ISBN 978-0-470-14765-8
  14. Kosse, Fabian; Deckers, Thomas; Pinger, Pia; Schildberg-Hoerisch, Hannah; Falk, Armin (2019-05-14). "The Formation of Prosociality: Causal Evidence on the Role of Social Environment". Journal of Political Economy. 128 (2): 434–467. doi:10.1086/704386. hdl:10419/162918. ISSN 0022-3808.
  15. Cappelen, Alexander; List, John; Samek, Anya; Tungodden, Bertil (December 2016). "The Effect of Early Education on Social Preferences" (PDF). Cambridge, MA: w22898. doi:10.3386/w22898. Cite journal requires |journal= (help)
  16. Batson, C. Daniel; Shaw, Laura L. (1991-04-01). "Evidence for Altruism: Toward a Pluralism of Prosocial Motives". Psychological Inquiry. 2 (2): 107–122. doi:10.1207/s15327965pli0202_1. ISSN 1047-840X.
  17. Hoffman, Martin L. (2001), "Toward a comprehensive empathy-based theory of prosocial moral development.", Constructive & destructive behavior: Implications for family, school, & society, American Psychological Association, pp. 61–86, doi:10.1037/10433-003, ISBN 1-55798-740-8
  18. Underwood, Bill; Moore, Bert (1982). "Perspective-taking and altruism". Psychological Bulletin. 91 (1): 143–173. doi:10.1037/0033-2909.91.1.143. ISSN 0033-2909.
  19. Eisenberg, Nancy; Zhou, Qing; Koller, Silvia (2001). "Brazilian Adolescents' Prosocial Moral Judgment and Behavior: Relations to Sympathy, Perspective Taking, Gender-Role Orientation, and Demographic Characteristics". Child Development. 72 (2): 518–534. doi:10.1111/1467-8624.00294. ISSN 1467-8624. PMID 11333082.
  20. Güth, Werner; Schmittberger, Rolf; Schwarze, Bernd (1982-12-01). "An experimental analysis of ultimatum bargaining" (PDF). Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization. 3 (4): 367–388. doi:10.1016/0167-2681(82)90011-7.
  21. Levitt, Steven D; List, John A (April 2007). "What Do Laboratory Experiments Measuring Social Preferences Reveal About the Real World?". Journal of Economic Perspectives. 21 (2): 153–174. doi:10.1257/jep.21.2.153.
  22. Forsythe, Robert; Horowitz, Joel L.; Savin, N.E.; Sefton, Martin (May 1994). "Fairness in Simple Bargaining Experiments". Games and Economic Behavior. 6 (3): 347–369. doi:10.1006/game.1994.1021.
  23. Berg, Joyce; Dickhaut, John; McCabe, Kevin (1995-07-01). "Trust, Reciprocity, and Social History". Games and Economic Behavior. 10 (1): 122–142. doi:10.1006/game.1995.1027.
  24. Fehr, Ernst; Kirchsteiger, Georg; Riedl, Arno (1993-05-01). "Does Fairness Prevent Market Clearing? An Experimental Investigation". The Quarterly Journal of Economics. 108 (2): 437–459. doi:10.2307/2118338. JSTOR 2118338.
  25. Kagel, John H.; Levin, Dan (2016-01-31). "9. Auctions A Survey of Experimental Research". The Handbook of Experimental Economics, Volume Two. Princeton University Press. doi:10.1515/9781400883172-010. ISBN 978-1-4008-8317-2.
  26. Kahneman, Daniel; Knetsch, Jack L.; Thaler, Richard H. (2000-09-25). "Fairness as a Constraint on Profit Seeking: Entitlements in the Market". Choices, Values, and Frames. Cambridge University Press. pp. 317–334. doi:10.1017/cbo9780511803475.019. ISBN 978-0-511-80347-5.
  27. Alm, James; Erard, Brian; Feinstein, Jonathan (May 1995). "The Relationship between State and Federal Tax Audits". Cambridge, MA. doi:10.3386/w5134. Cite journal requires |journal= (help)
  28. Lind, E. Allan; Tyler, Tom R. (1988). "The Social Psychology of Procedural Justice". Critical Issues in Social Justice. doi:10.1007/978-1-4899-2115-4. ISBN 978-1-4899-2117-8.
  29. Gneezy, Uri; List, John A (September 2006). "Putting Behavioral Economics to Work: Testing for Gift Exchange in Labor Markets Using Field Experiments" (PDF). Econometrica. 74 (5): 1365–1384. doi:10.1111/j.1468-0262.2006.00707.x.
  30. Kube, Sebastian; Maréchal, Michel André; Puppe, Clemens (2013-07-24). "Do Wage Cuts Damage Work Morale? Evidence from a Natural Field Experiment" (PDF). Journal of the European Economic Association. 11 (4): 853–870. doi:10.1111/jeea.12022.
  31. Breza, Emily; Kaur, Supreet; Shamdasani, Yogita (2018-05-01). "The Morale Effects of Pay Inequality". The Quarterly Journal of Economics. 133 (2): 611–663. doi:10.1093/qje/qjx041.
  32. Charness, Gary; Rabin, Matthew (2000). "Understanding Social Preference with Simple Tests". doi:10.2139/ssrn.224577. Cite journal requires |journal= (help)
  33. Fehr, Ernst; Schmidt, Klaus M. (2006). "Chapter 8. The Economics of Fairness, Reciprocity and Altruism – Experimental Evidence and New Theories". In Kolm, Serge-Christophe; Ythier, Jean Mercier (eds.). Handbook of the Economics of Giving, Altruism and Reciprocity. Foundations. 1. Elsevier. pp. 615–691. doi:10.1016/s1574-0714(06)01008-6. ISBN 9780444506979.
  34. Levine, David K. (1998-07-01). "Modeling Altruism and Spitefulness in Experiments". Review of Economic Dynamics. 1 (3): 593–622. doi:10.1006/redy.1998.0023.
  35. Andreoni, James (1990-06-01). "Impure Altruism and Donations to Public Goods: A Theory of Warm-Glow Giving". The Economic Journal. 100 (401): 464–477. doi:10.2307/2234133. JSTOR 2234133.
  36. Fehr, Ernst; Schmidt, Klaus M. (1999-08-01). "A Theory of Fairness, Competition, and Cooperation" (PDF). The Quarterly Journal of Economics. 114 (3): 817–868. doi:10.1162/003355399556151.
  37. Bolton, Gary E; Ockenfels, Axel (March 2000). "ERC: A Theory of Equity, Reciprocity, and Competition" (PDF). American Economic Review. 90 (1): 166–193. CiteSeerX 10.1.1.198.5074. doi:10.1257/aer.90.1.166.
  38. Charness, Gary; Rabin, Matthew (2002-08-01). "Understanding Social Preferences with Simple Tests". The Quarterly Journal of Economics. 117 (3): 817–869. doi:10.1162/003355302760193904. JSTOR 4132490.
  39. Rabin, Matthew (2011). "Incorporating Fairness into Game Theory and Economics". Advances in Behavioral Economics. Princeton University Press. pp. 297–325. doi:10.2307/j.ctvcm4j8j.15. ISBN 978-1-4008-2911-8.
  40. Dufwenberg, Martin; Kirchsteiger, Georg (May 2004). "A theory of sequential reciprocity" (PDF). Games and Economic Behavior. 47 (2): 268–298. doi:10.1016/j.geb.2003.06.003.
  41. Falk, Armin; Fischbacher, Urs (2006-02-01). "A theory of reciprocity". Games and Economic Behavior. 54 (2): 293–315. doi:10.1016/j.geb.2005.03.001.
  42. Fehr, Ernst; Fischbacher, Urs (2002). "Why Social Preferences Matter – the Impact of non‐Selfish Motives on Competition, Cooperation and Incentives". The Economic Journal. 112 (478): C1–C33. doi:10.1111/1468-0297.00027. hdl:20.500.11850/146625. JSTOR 798356. SSRN 299142.
  43. Card, David; Mas, Alexandre; Moretti, Enrico; Saez, Emmanuel (2012). "Inequality at Work: The Effect of Peer Salaries on Job Satisfaction". American Economic Review. 102 (6): 2981–3003. doi:10.1257/aer.102.6.2981.
  44. Bowles, Samuel; Polanía-Reyes, Sandra (2012). "Economic Incentives and Social Preferences: Substitutes or Complements?" (PDF). Journal of Economic Literature. 50 (2): 368–425. doi:10.1257/jel.50.2.368.
  45. Wax, Amy L. (2000). "Rethinking Welfare Rights: Reciprocity Norms, Reactive Attitudes, and the Political Economy of Welfare Reform". Law and Contemporary Problems. 63 (1): 257–298. doi:10.2139/ssrn.198928.
This article is issued from Wikipedia. The text is licensed under Creative Commons - Attribution - Sharealike. Additional terms may apply for the media files.