Impartial culture

Impartial culture (IC) or the culture of indifference[1] is a probabilistic model used in social choice theory for analyzing ranked voting method rules.[2][3]

The model is understood to be unrealistic, and not a good representation of real-world voting behavior, however, it is useful for mathematical comparisons of voting methods under reproducible, worst-case scenarios.[4][5][6][1][7]

The model assumes that each voter provides a complete strict ranking of all the candidates (with no equal rankings or blanks), which is drawn from a set of all possible rankings. For candidates, there are possible strict rankings (permutations).[2]

There are three variations of the model that use different subsets of the full set of possible rankings, so that different election permutations are drawn with different probabilities:

Impartial Culture (IC)

This model assumes that each voter's ranking is randomly selected from a uniform distribution. If these are chosen by voters, there are thus possible elections ("preference profiles".)[2]

Impartial Anonymous Culture (IAC)

This reduces the set of possible elections by eliminating those that are equivalent if the voter identities are unknown.[2][8] For example, the two-candidate, three-voter election {A>B, A>B, B>A} is equivalent to the election where the second and third voters swap votes: {A>B, B>A, A>B}, and so all variations on this set of votes are only included once. The set of all such elections is called the anonymous equivalence class (AEC), and if the strict rankings are being chosen by voters, there are possible elections[2]

Impartial, Anonymous, and Neutral Culture (IANC)

This reduces the set of possible elections further, by eliminating those that are equivalent if the candidate identities are unknown. For example, the two-candidate, three-voter election {A>B, A>B, B>A} is equivalent to the election where the two candidates are swapped: {B>A, B>A, A>B}.[2]

References

  1. Van Deemen, Adrian (2014). "On the empirical relevance of Condorcet's paradox". Public Choice. 158 (3–4): 311–330. doi:10.1007/s11127-013-0133-3. ISSN 0048-5829. The impartial culture assumption has been criticized extensively as being implausible and empirically irrelevant
  2. Eğecioğlu, Ömer; Giritligil, Ayça E. (October 2013). "The Impartial, Anonymous, and Neutral Culture Model: A Probability Model for Sampling Public Preference Structures" (PDF). The Journal of Mathematical Sociology. 37 (4): 203–222. doi:10.1080/0022250X.2011.597012. ISSN 0022-250X.
  3. Guilbaud, Georges-Théodule (2012). "Les théories de l'intérêt général et le problème logique de l'agrégation". Revue économique (in French). 63 (4): 659. doi:10.3917/reco.634.0659. ISSN 0035-2764.
  4. Lehtinen, Aki; Kuorikoski, Jaakko (2007). "Unrealistic Assumptions in Rational Choice Theory". Philosophy of the Social Sciences. 37 (2): 115–138. doi:10.1177/0048393107299684. ISSN 0048-3931. ...Using unrealistic assumptions may thus have a reasonable methodological function even if we know how to describe reality in a more realistic way...
  5. Tsetlin, Ilia; Regenwetter, Michel; Grofman, Bernard (2003-12-01). "The impartial culture maximizes the probability of majority cycles". Social Choice and Welfare. 21 (3): 387–398. doi:10.1007/s00355-003-0269-z. ISSN 0176-1714. it is widely acknowledged that the impartial culture is unrealistic ... the impartial culture is the worst case scenario
  6. Tideman, T; Plassmann, Florenz (June 2008). "The Source of Election Results: An Empirical Analysis of Statistical Models of Voter Behavior". Voting theorists generally acknowledge that they consider this model to be unrealistic Cite journal requires |journal= (help)
  7. Gehrlein, William V.; Lepelley, Dominique (2011), "Voting Paradoxes and Their Probabilities", Voting Paradoxes and Group Coherence, Springer Berlin Heidelberg, pp. 1–47, doi:10.1007/978-3-642-03107-6_1, ISBN 9783642031069, if we use conditions that tend to exaggerate the likelihood of observing paradoxes and find that the probability is small with such calculations, the paradox is assuredly very unlikely to be observed in reality.
  8. Veselova, Yuliya A. (2014). "Comparing Probabilistic Models : IC , IAC , IANC". www.semanticscholar.org. Retrieved 2019-07-16.


This article is issued from Wikipedia. The text is licensed under Creative Commons - Attribution - Sharealike. Additional terms may apply for the media files.